What should be done about an increasingly aggressive Russia? The past few weeks have brought more evidence of Moscow’s move away from international norms and law.
By Christopher Hartwell and Andreas Umland
Image Attribute: President of Russia Vladimir Putin / Source: The Conversation
What should be done about an increasingly aggressive Russia? The past few weeks have brought more evidence of Moscow’s move away from international norms and law. From continued denials of complicity in the MH17 tragedy and the bombing of a humanitarian convoy in Syria to Russian President Vladimir Putin’s recent exit from the Nuclear Security Pact with the US, Russia’s behavior is diverging further from the rules-based consensus of the post-Cold War world. This is in spite of Western sanctions that were introduced against Moscow in 2014.
Indeed, these moderate limitations on selling certain goods and services to Russia as well as on the freedom of movement of some Russians seem to have emboldened Putin. With a new debate underway in the EU and US on the future of the sanctions regime, there may now be a window of opportunity for significantly expanding economic measures, including financial or personal sanctions, in order to bring Russia back from the brink of military escalation. The West has powerful non-military tools for dealing with a belligerent Russia, given Moscow’s high reliance on energy exports. But increased sanctions need to be predicated on a clear metric of what they are intended to achieve.
Often discussions of these issues refer to lessons learned from earlier embargoes against other countries. What was the relative effectiveness of trade and other limitations in altering political behavior? Scholarship such as Gary C. Hufbauer’s classic Economic Sanctions Reconsidered or recent work from Bryan Early has shown that economic sanctions have often tended to be poorly designed and, as a result, largely futile. Does past experience indicate that sanctions are doomed to be ineffectual?
The poor record of earlier sanctions against Iran, North Korea or Cuba are only partly applicable to the Russian case. To be sure, Russia is like these countries, a non-democratic state with elements of despotism and a large state-controlled sector of the economy. But its economy is more deeply integrated into global trade, finance, and investment patterns than many of the past targets of sanctions. The Russian elite is heavily Westernized and interacts in a multitude of ways with the EU and other countries or allies of the West. About half of the Russian state budget consists of income from foreign trade—above all, from revenues related to the export of crude oil.
And that makes the Kremlin unusually vulnerable to economic pressure. If the sanctions’ goal is inflicting economic damage to make foreign adventurism costlier and thus cause policy changes, there are a number of ways in which sanctions could achieve this aim. Unlike the sanctions regime currently in place, import rather than export sanctions targeted at the Achilles heel of the Russian economy, oil trade, could make a difference and have a quick political impact.
The West could, in a first step, reduce Moscow’s state income from energy exports through a reduction or outright ban of Russian oil imports. As a second step, it could further increase pressure by threatening to also sanction, as the US once did to Iran, non-Western companies that buy oil from or transport oil from Russia or that otherwise assist Moscow's energy trade—that is, a worldwide embargo.
This would have serious repercussions for Russia’s regime. First, in view of the state budget’s massive reliance on oil trade revenues, the Kremlin’s available room to maneuver on the international stage would be reduced, and make new foreign adventures less likely. Second, because of the close relationship between the ruble’s exchange rate and Russian energy trade, the country’s entire economy would quickly dive—perhaps even at the mere announcement of import sanctions. Third, all economic actors in Moscow, whether Russian or foreign, know of the country’s overwhelming energy dependence and fear the above scenario. Not only energy traders but also other businesses would quickly adapt their economic behavior, with likely cascading effects like capital outflow, bank runs, or project cancellations.
These measures would not only trigger a major social crisis in Russia because of price hikes. They would also eventually strike at the Russian military-industrial complex. Putin cannot afford politically to simply cut down pensions, salaries, stipends, and social subsidies in order to continue financing his instruments of hybrid war at their current level. This also makes sustained Russian counter-sanctions, such as a reduction of natural gas exports to the EU, unlikely. Once the Russian state and economy have been hit by Western import sanctions, the Kremlin would be unable to further reduce foreign trade income through prolonged counter-sanctions.
Harming the energy sector would force Moscow to make difficult choices regarding its priorities. So far, mainly ordinary Russians have felt the bite of the combined effects of oil price slumps and Western export sanctions since 2014. However, certain sectors of the elite have been relatively insulated from the effects of these economic changes. With Western energy import reductions, insulating elite members of society from income losses would become more difficult.
Could such a strategy backfire? The economic turmoil ensuing from such sanctions could create, many argue, a Russia even worse than the current version. For instance, Putin could become, or be replaced by, a more radically anti-Western and aggressive leader. However, a hypothetical Russian fascist regime would still be faced with the challenge of paying basic salaries and pensions as well as generating enough income to keep the social system intact. It is unlikely that the current regime will be replaced by one even less able to restore trade relations with the West and secure critical revenues for Russia’s embattled state budget.
Another open question is what effect these sanctions would have on energy prices globally. With the EU still suffering from aftereffects of the global financial crisis, some fear new economic disruptions from a Russian-Western trade war. However, one must remember that as recently as June 2014, almost six years after Lehman Brothers went bankrupt, Brent oil was at $112 per barrel. Only in the past two years oil prices have dropped precipitously due to increasing supply because of the shale oil revolution and other technological advances. Given the current oversupply of crude oil on the world market and the eagerness of Moscow's competitors to replace Russian energy companies in Western markets, the world economic repercussions of a reduction of EU oil imports from Siberia will thus be limited.
A more important point for debate is how to properly match future sanctions to desired outcomes. There has been insufficient articulation over the past two years of what exactly the current modest sanctions are designed to achieve. For instance, the major sanctions introduced in summer 2014 were, later on in 2014-2015, linked to the fulfillment of both Minsk agreements. Oddly, the prospect of their cancellation or prolongation is thus now also connected to those parts of the agreements that refer to Ukraine’s domestic affairs. In the worst case, the current sanctions could be cancelled because Kyiv does not fulfill its obligations under the Minsk agreements – although these agreements did not yet exist when the major sanctions were introduced in summer 2014.
More generally: Will the goal of the current and new future sanctions be to signal support for Kyiv’s European choice, to freeze the Russian-Ukrainian conflict, to deter Moscow from aggression elsewhere, to remove Russia from the Donbas, to end the Kremlin’s hybrid war against Ukraine, to make Putin hand back Crimea, to halt Russian humanitarian atrocities in Syria, or a combination of these – or something else? The so far unclear political rationale, underlying philosophy and final objective of the West’s sanctions makes new decisions to tighten them difficult. Until now, there is no clear sense of when exactly which sanctions should be regarded as having achieved their objectives or when not.
The West has enormous economic leverage against Moscow. But before using it, it must properly understand, jointly decide and publicly announce what precisely the sanctions are aimed at. Without such clarification, the prolongation of the old and introduction of new sanctions may induce more hardship for the Russian people but result in little change in the Kremlin’s policies.
About the Authors:
Christopher A. Hartwell is president of the Center for Social and Economic Research in Warsaw, a non-resident associate fellow at the Institute for Euro-Atlantic Cooperation in Kyiv, and the author of “Two Roads Diverge : The Transition Experience of Poland and Ukraine,” published by Cambridge University Press.
Andreas Umland is a senior research fellow at the Institute for Euro-Atlantic Cooperation in Kyiv as well as general editor of the book series “Soviet and Post-Soviet Politics and Society” and consulting editor for the “Journal of Soviet and Post-Soviet Politics and Society,” both distributed outside Europe by Columbia University Press.
Cite the Article:
Hartwell, C.A , Umland, A. "OPINION | Reluctance and Reality: The Case for More Effectual Economic Sanctions against an Increasingly Bellicose Russ ia" IndraStra Global Vol. 002, Issue No: 11 (2016), 0007 http://www.indrastra.com/2016/11/OPINION-Reluctance-and-Reality-002-11-2016-0007.html | ISSN 2381-3652